Futbolun Ekonomi Politiği Mümkün mü?
Bizi Takip Edin Futbol ekonomisi facebookta futbol ekonomisi twitterde
x
Hata
  • JUser::_load: Unable to load user with id: 62
Buradasınız >> Ana Sayfa IN ENGLISH Economy Futbolun Ekonomi Politiği Mümkün mü?

Futbolun Ekonomi Politiği Mümkün mü?

statyum1

Futbolun ekonomisi ve politiği üzerine çeşitli çalışmaları bulunan Prof.Dr.Wyn Grant "Is a political economy of football" başlıklı Nisan 2006'daki çalışması gerçekten çok ilginç gözlemler ve tespitler içeriyor.

 Futbolun politik ekonomisi bildiğimiz anlamda politik iktisattan çok önemli farklılıklar gösteriyor. Taraftar sadakati, tüketici rasyonelliğini mezara gömmektedir. Bu anlamda futbolun politik iktisadı, tüketici taraftarın tüketim kalıplarını ve politikalarını belirlemede  çok etkin değildir. Endüstriyelleşen futbolla birlikte futbol taraftarı çok özel bir müşteri/tüketici türüne dönüşmüştür. Bu bağlamda futbol tüketicisinin futbolun ekonomi politiğindeki yeri ve önemi yadsınamaz. Futbolun giderek milyar dolarlık bir endüstriye dönüşmesi  başta futbol kulüplerinin olmak üzere futbolun tüm ögelerini önemli bir değişikliğe uğratmıştır. Gelirlerin artması kulüpler arasındaki rekabeti de olumsuz etkilemiş, zamanla haksız rekabet büyük kulüplerin lehine dönmüştür. Bu nedenle futbol gelirlerinin paylaşımı futbolun politik iktisadını da doğurmuştur. İşte Warwick Üniversitesi Profesörlerinden Wyn Grant'ın bu incelemesi bize gerçekten önemli ışık tutuyor. Son derec akıcı bir dilde ve basit, anlaşılır bir şekilde kaleme aldığı bu çalışmasını sizinle paylaşıyoruz.

 

Is A Political Economy of Football Possible?

Prof. Dr. Wyn Grant

 

Department of olitics and International Studies, University of Warwick and www.footballeconomy.com

Is a political economy of football possible?    The assumption made in this paper is that it is.   Otherwise there would be no point in proceeding any further.   However, it is also argued that the construction of such a political economy is a difficult, fraught and problematic exercise.    In part, this has to do with issues about the nature of political economy as an intellectual enterprise, but it also arises from particular features of football as a sport, business, source of identity etc.    Hence, bringing the two together is a journey full of pitfalls.   The attempt made here is both tentative and speculative, very much of a bringing together of thoughts and reflections generated rather incoherently over a long period of time.

     This paper is about a political economy of football rather than a political economy of sport and the relationship between the two is left unexplored here.   Should a political economy of football be a subset of a more general political economy of sport?   Constructing a political economy of sport would be an even more ambitious effort and would require knowledge about a range of sports that the writer does not possess.   There is case, however, for looking at football on its own.  ‘Association football … is without question the world’s most popular sport … Some estimates value soccer-related business at over £250 billion in the year 2003.’  (Guilianotti, 2005, p. 19).

      This paper does not deal systematically with questions of identity in relation to football, except in so far as they are necessary to an understanding of the economic dynamics of the sport.    This is not to deny the importance of such cultural understandings of football.    The football club forms part of an identity as reflected in the song ‘I’m [name of club] until I die.’   Indeed, Conn (2005) argues ‘As other collective institutions disappear, football clubs are becoming an increasingly central part of people’s identity.’   These considerations are important, but to explore them systematically would be to overload the paper.

       This paper identifies with those analysts who want to revert to a more classical understanding of political economy and remove the ‘I’ from international political economy and the ‘C’ from comparative political economy.    Thus, ‘the attachment of the “C” and the “I” to a term that already by definition encompasses both of these is, in the first place, unnecessary and, in the second, counterproductive in that it has occasioned an unhelpful disciplinary fragmentation and a range of unhappy consequences for the theoretical and empirical study of contemporary political economy.’  (Phillips, 2004, p. 265).  Football is an activity that is organised at an international, regional, national (and, of course, local) level.   It therefore needs the insights about globalisation and its effects generated within the international political economy paradigm, but also the sensitivity to national differences arising from debates about varieties of capitalism, as well as an understanding of the increasing significance of regional actors, particularly the European Union (EU).   ‘A dominant theme’ that emerges from one analysis of the political economy of sport ‘is the accelerated expansion of transnational capitalism and its extension into the sport/cultural realm.’   (Schimmel, 2005, p. 3).    However, the expansion of capitalist values into football has met with a politics of resistance, not least from community based movements mobilising to defend their club.    Such movements have been able to draw on fans’ identification with their club which is all the stronger for the fact that it in terms of geography it is often sentimental and constructed.   Whether such movements are effective is an issue that is returned to later.

      This paper attempts to avoid an excessive eclecticism which is a natural temptation when an area of enquiry is finding its feet.   There is much to be said for approaches ‘that are eclectic in their use of historical, cultural, economic and sociological evidence to support their analyses.’  (Schimmel, 2005, p. 2).   The approach adopted here is one of ‘controlled eclecticism’.  (Phillips, 2004, p. 15).  In other words, there is openness to a variety of approaches and perspectives, but also an insistence on a certain level of parsimony and coherence in the selection of theories and methodologies.   This is not to argue that approaches other than the ones adopted here are invalid or inappropriate.  At its simplest, it is to argue that one needs one’s own voice which others can identify, respond to and criticise.

       It is also worth noting that the world of football constitutes a clearly defined policy community with clear boundaries, underpinned by its own rituals and technical expertise, with a high political entry price.   Measured against the advance of the regulatory state (Moran, 2005), it has continued to enjoy considerable autonomy in its governance arrangements, despite a series of evident failures.   Government has, however, been largely content to let the Football Association (FA) put its own house in order.  This is all the more remarkable when one considers that football generally lacks sophistication when it comes to political questions.   Many clubs were slow to appreciate just what the EU could do with its competition policy powers and it was really the giant clubs that were able to appreciate the seriousness of the situation and respond accordingly.   In other words, a ‘company state’ model prevailed over the ‘associative state’ model represented by Uefa.  Many clubs, however, continue to resent the intervention of the EU through the application of general competition laws to their special sector.   As one Premiership chairman put it:

      The European Commission continues to involve itself in the affairs of the FA

      Premier League in a very public and high profile manner.  …. It cannot be right that

      the Commission should seek to challenge our right to enter into genuine commercial

      agreements for the sale of our broadcast rights because they do not like the outcome.

      We must use every means at our disposal to protect the game in this country from

      such outside interference.   (Murray, 2005,p. 5).

As far as the European Commission is concerned, football as a multi-billon euro business activity cannot be exempted from the competition rules designed to deal with abuses of economic power through monopolies and cartels, although the deal reached on the FA Premier League’s television rights, after much talk of a crackdown, represents a very good outcome for the Premiership.

      In summary, we have what has been a highly insulated sector of economy and society being buffeted by forces that it does not always fully comprehend, let alone be able to effectively control.  The lack of sophistication means that although politics undoubtedly matters in football, it matters in a particular way.   The political is perceived as a largely malign force external to a policy community that should be allowed to regulate its own affairs.   This makes exogenously driven political change quite difficult.   It is also means that the discourse of depoliticisation that has been applied so effectively to the understanding of much of contemporary economic policy cannot be deployed so readily in the case of football.   In a sense, it has to be politicised before it can depoliticised.

Meanings of political economy

This paper aspires to move towards ‘a political economy that privileges neither politicism nor economism’.  (Phillips, 2005a, p. 251).   In engaging in the study of political economy, ‘drawing stark boundaries between the various branches of the social sciences concerned with political economy is neither helpful nor appropriate.’  (Phillips, 2005a, p. 252).  Contrary to the liberal view that one has to make a separation between state and market and their study, it is contended that ‘politics and economics are intrinsically inseparable, and that this inseparability must be represented in the primary theoretical and methodological approaches to the study of IPE.’   (Phillips, 2005a, p. 250).   The challenge is then to decide what constitutes ‘an appropriate integration of … politics and economics’.  (Phillips, 2005a, p. 250).    Here I would adhere to a view I set out a long time ago:

       In talking of a ‘political economy’, one is not advocating a hybridization of the two

       subjects which would inevitably mean that the economics strain would be dominant.

       Rather it is argued that both disciplines need to bring their own particular insights to

       bear on problems of common interest … By proceeding in this way not only is an

       understanding of the specific problem enhanced, but the two disciplines can be

       enriched by a better understanding of the theories, methodology and terminology of

       the other discipline.  (Grant, 1982, p. 3).

Two views of economics

Two polar views need to be rejected if we are to proceed successfully.   One is the view taken by some economists that there is an economic explanation of everything:

        Morality, it could be argued, represents the way that people would like the world

        to work – whereas economics represents how it actually does work.  …

        [Economics] comprises an extraordinarily powerful and flexible set of tools

        that can reliably assess a thicket of information to determine the effect of any one

        factor, or even the whole effect.  (Levitt and Dubner, 2005, p.13).

 Economic explanations do have wide applications and the fact that rationality is bounded does not necessarily undermine them.   The unease expressed here is a normative rather than an analytical one.   Making economic explanations predominate can encourage a process of commodification and it could be argued that sport should be added to Polanyi’s list of land, labour and money as entities that should not be treated as commodities.   The methodological individualism of economics can lead to an understatement of the value of collective structures in a society that bind it together, its social capital, with sports clubs being one specific example.   ‘Economic liberalism is in this sense a victim of its own propaganda: offered to all, it has evoked pressures and demands that cannot be contained.’  (Hirsch, 1977, p. 70).  

    Adam Smith reminded us that a society cannot function on the basis of benevolence alone, but it also needs a rough balance between self-regarding and socially oriented behaviour.   Too rigid an application of the lessons of economics might encourage more self-regarding behaviour.   An experiment conducted by Marwell and Ames found that economics graduate students were more likely to free ride and were less concerned with fairness than other subjects.  Thus ‘they may start behaving according to the tenets of the theories they study.’  (Marwell and Ames, 1981, p. 309).   How economists conduct themselves might seem to be a relatively trivial matter but the broader issue is ‘an increasingly rules-based and technocratic approach to economic governance, in which the functions of [the] state are seen to be twofold: first to underpin markets, and, second, to address market failures through the provision of various rights and goods.’   (Phillips, 2005b, p. 105).

       One therefore needs to be aware of the limits of economics and the dangers of its seductive embrace.   However, one also needs to reject the opposite view, represented for example by Susan Strange, which amounts to ‘always attack the economists’.   Strange had a number of objections to economists and to liberal economists in particular, issuing a clarion call to students of international political economy to throw off ‘the intellectual bondage of liberal economics’.  (Strange, 2002a, p. 47).   One of her central objections, not an unfamiliar charge to be levelled against economists, was:

       [M]ost economists tacitly share certain fundamental assumptions about the

       rationality of buyers and sellers in the marketplace, or about the easy

       availability of information regarding supply and demand that happen to be

       convenient for economic argument but which do not always accord with everyday

       experience.  (Strange, 2002b, p. 121).

Information asymmetries are in fact a central feature of discussions of market failure in economics, but her more central objection appears to be that economists engage in model building.   In other words, they make simplifying assumptions that allow them to generate robust models that have explanatory and/or predictive value, even if they are an approximate fit to the whole range of experience. 

      Perhaps her real objection is ‘the study of economics is led and dominated by the United States’ (Strange, 2002c, p.190), although the same observation could be made of political science and international relations, not that it prevents the development of distinctive British theoretical and empirical perspectives.   There is, however, perhaps something in her observation that economics exhibits ‘a certain political naiveté in its conclusions.’  (Strange, 2002c, p. 190).  Economics tends to regard the choice of policy instruments as a second order question, whereas for a student of public policy they are of central importance and linked to broader theoretical debates such as that about the regulatory state.

The position taken here

 The broad position adopted here is that economic explanations can take us so far and indeed cannot be avoided.   However, whilst they are necessary, they are never sufficient.   Other forms of explanation are needed, but not simply as supplements to compensate for any deficiencies in the main analytical dish.   As noted above, the real challenge is to decide on the appropriate integration of economics and politics and this task will be returned to in the conclusion.  The methodology adopted in the intervening discussion is first to take some central economic concepts and apply them to the case of football.   One of the findings to emerge is that football as a ‘market’ has some very distinctive characteristics.   The limitations of an economic analysis are illustrated through a discussion of whether fans should be designated as ‘customers’ or supporters.    Having seen how far economic analysis can take us, particularly in terms of bringing out the distinctiveness of football, we then consider how a political analysis might be brought into the discussion.

       Before proceeding to an economic analysis of football, let us briefly considered in stylised terms the ways in which it has changed as an economic sector in recent years.      In the 1990s the nature of football as an enterprise changed with clubs becoming more like other businesses in the way that they were run.    A number of leading clubs, not just in the United Kingdom, were floated on stock exchanges, often realising considerable profits for the existing shareholders.   Although not attracting the attendances of baseball, American football, or basketball, football (or soccer) was successfully introduced into the key US market.     Revenue streams increased considerably as television revenues grew rapidly with the advent of satellite and cable television, higher ticket prices, more effective marketing of merchandise and more lucrative corporate sponsorship.   Football’s profitability became interlocked with that of the media industry and associated with this was a closer intersection between football and the cult of celebrity.  Clubs like Manchester United developed into global brands.   The fan, however, had to pay more to watch the game and more to wear the official choice of team shirt.   Fans were able to buy shares in their own clubs, but these gave only the illusion of ownership as Manchester United fans found when their shareholdings were unable to halt the takeover of the club by the Glazer family.

An economic analysis of football

Fan loyalty and elasticity of demand

A common proposition about football is that it is a very unusual market because of the intense loyalty of customers to a particular brand.   Because of their loyalty to their club, fans are open to exploitation, indeed among fans that is almost a shared definition of what they are.   They have to put up with very high prices, club merchandise with high price marks ups, inconvenient kick off times and indifferent and over priced food sold in stadiums because the option of exit is not a feasible one.   The disgruntled fan has a number of options available: stop attending at all; start supporting another club; or watch another sport.   Loyalty is an obstacle to the second option and, in any case, other clubs may charge just as much.    If one starts watching a non-league club, the standard of play and facilities will be inferior.   Switching to another sport is an unlikely option.   To put it in technical language, both for other teams and other sports, the cross-price elasticity of demand is ‘near zero.’  (Sandy, Sloan and Rosentraub, 2004, p. 7).

      The simple exit option is the most likely, but is often taken for reasons such as changes in family or working circumstances.   It also has to be remembered that going to a football match is as much a social event as a sporting experience.   Season ticket holders can enjoy the company of the same group of people year after year, and even if they don’t like some of them very much, that can be part of the experience.   The judgements of the ‘Bloke Behind Me’ can be a source of enjoyment because they are humorous, whether intentionally or because they are so ridiculous.   Visiting the pub before and after the game also serves as a social focus for renewing and making friendships.   For many fans, attending the match is a way of keeping in contact with old friends or a cherished set of locations (including, of course, the ground itself) they would not otherwise visit.   Sentiment and habit can be powerful forces in maintaining patterns of behaviour.

       It might then seem that partisanship and brand loyalty makes football a very special market.   However, a note of caution is necessary.   The price elasticity of demand for tickets is actually quite difficult to calculate.   In practice, however, ticket prices are increasingly varied (although in general not as much as they should be) to take account of differential demand for different games.    Clubs should perhaps take more account of the benefits derived from ancillary sales in setting prices and also the contribution that fans make to the atmosphere of a televised game.    What is striking is that English football supporters can pay four times as much as their counterparts in other top leagues to watch matches.    Even taking the cheapest season ticket, it can cost over three times as much to watch football at Arsenal or Chelsea as the most expensive club elsewhere (Barcelona). (www.footballeconomy.com, 26 August 2004).

       More generally, it is possible to over estimate both the unlikelihood of the exit option and the partisan loyalty of fans.   It should be recalled that ‘between the late 1940s and the late 1980s, football lost over half its spectators.’  (Szymanski and Kuypers, 2000, p. 46).   The missing fans were replaced by a more family oriented fan base as the hooliganism problem, at least in grounds, was tackled by new technology and stadiums were modernised and made more comfortable.   However, these new fans may be more fickle and there is anecdotal evidence that the fan base is ageing at the older clubs because of pricing policies.  (Conn, 2004, p. 11).   Perhaps too readily and understandably the image of the fan is often constructed around a single male who is obsessive about his football club and whose whole life is built around it.   Football supporters are actually a more diverse group.    However, despite the panic about falling attendances in the autumn of 2004, there is as yet little sign of price resistance in general, although it may be evident at clubs in more economically deprived areas such as Middlesbrough.   However, Premiership attendances in 2005/6 are forecast to fall by 0.44 per cent or 148 fewer fans per game.  (Cameron, 2005, p. 30).

     Fans can be more fickle than is sometime assumed.   Fans like to assert that they have always followed one club through thick and thin and may develop a familiarity with famous events in the club’s history so that they can claim that they were there at those vital moments.   It should be noted that ‘beyond the hard core there are many supporters who are willing to switch allegiance towards more successful teams.’  (Szymanski and Kuypers, 2000, p. 190).     Or, one might add, a more convenient team.   Despite all the unfavourable publicity they attracted, and relatively poor performances on the pitch, Milton Keynes Dons have attracted bigger crowds than I or most analysts would have predicted. 

       Relatively stable aggregate attendance figures conceal a great deal of churn in their actual composition and the new fans could be expected to be less loyal than those who have been fans for many years (indeed, they may be stigmatised as ‘glory hunters’ by more established fans).   Football and partisanship may seem to be inseparable, but there are those who are interested in technical exhibitions of skill.   Fulham Football Club has an area for ‘neutral’ fans and this seemed to be a contradiction in terms.   Given that there are likely to be few, if any, fans following their favourite man in black around the country, it seemed likely that this area would be populated by away fans unable to get seats in their own area.   To some extent this is the case, but after a game at Fulham, I actually met a neutral who had come to enjoy the match as a spectacle, suggesting that Fulham may have actually discovered a niche market.

      Brand loyalty is exceptionally high in football, particularly compared to other product markets, and this does constrain the use of the exit option and create a relatively inelastic pattern of demand.    However, one must be careful of overstating this effect, particularly against a background of growing fan dissatisfaction with high player wages and the prices they are required to pay for enjoying football in England

Exit by clubs

It has been argued that in Europe ‘there are too many clubs given the overall population.’

(Sandy, Sloan and Rosentraub, 2004, pp. 22-23).   In terms of revenue generation, this problem is compounded by the fact that teams are not granted exclusive territorial franchises on the American model that create a local monopoly, so there may be a large number of clubs in a single metropolitan area (just think of Manchester and the surrounding towns).   An entrepreneur wishing to establish a new club may have to settle for an area where there are few ‘chimney pots’, Rushden and Diamonds situated in Irthlingborough which is little more than a large village offers a classic example.    The only populated area of any size in England where there are no clubs is Cornwall, which has a strong rugby tradition (fans in eastern Cornwall can support Plymouth).

     Why, then, do so few league clubs go out of business?    The relatively few examples are ingrained on the collective consciousness of fans: Accrington Stanley, Maidstone United, Third Lanark etc. and two of the examples cited have re-formed, albeit at lower levels of competition.    Because the existence of the club is so important to the identity of many fans, they will dig deep in their pockets to keep the club going, with fans living abroad who have not been near the club for years among the most generous donors.   Even people who are not fans of the club may be persuaded to donate.   Moreover, administration is a useful reorganising device with the St. John’s Ambulance and local businesses invariably not getting their outstanding bills paid.    Once the club is in administration, a wealthy business person may arrive on the scene to acquire it at a knock down price, although not necessarily as a good business proposition (which it often is not unless there is unrealised property value).    Indeed, ‘the owners of clubs are frequently wealthy fans who may treat their team not as a business but rather as a consumption activity from which they derive utility.’  (Sandy, Sloan and Rosentraub, 2004, p. 11).

      Paradoxically, in conventional markets, ‘it is often the more efficient firms [that] exit, leaving the less efficient firms behind.’  (Grant, 1989, p. 25).   The resistance to exit in football markets may not therefore necessarily be undesirable.    There is a clear clash between a market rationale which may suggest that there should be fewer teams which would, in principle, lead to a higher revenue stream for those remaining and the view generally held by fans that all clubs in existence should be allowed to survive.   Mergers are a conventional reorganisation device in most markets, but are relatively rare in football.    Inverness Caledonian Thistle is the only recent successful example.  One problem is that most mergers are in fact ‘takeovers’ where either the identity of one company is subsumed in another or where distinct brand identities are preserved after the merger, an option not feasible in football given strict rules on dual ownership and ‘nursery clubs’ (although there might be a case for relaxing the latter to help struggling lower division teams).    Even the apparently more innocuous option of ground sharing can attract strong fan objections because of the extent to which their identity is bound up with the stadium, although an ingenious solution at non-league level has been for Erith and Belvedere to build their own stand and headquarters on one side of Welling’s ground.  Thus, as far as the number of enterprises in the football market is concerned, or even the facilities they use, community oriented values win out over the logic of the market.

Joint production and club dominance

Football, like other sports, ‘differs from other businesses because it requires joint production.’  (Sandy, Sloane and Rosentraub, 2004, p. 157).   Teams need other teams to compete against and a league offers a more structured and interesting format for such competition which is why they were formed in the first place.   However, a league can be constituted in a number of different ways, size and hence frequency of matches between its members being one variable, while relegation and promotion rules are another.  Above all, a key issue is whether the league is structured in such a way as to promote uncertainty of outcome, both in particular matches and across the season as a whole.    There are a number of devices for making leagues more competitive ranging from sharing attendance money with away teams to player drafts.    The rationale for seeking to enhance unpredictability is to maximise entertainment value for the fans.

     ‘The most significant issue that now confronts all leagues in North America and the UK is competitive balance.’   (Sandy, Sloan and Rosentraub, 2004, p. 177).   Owners have an interest in winning as many games as possible so maximise revenue, given that success attracts crowds and television revenue.   Hence, ‘The real issue may well be the inherent conflict between owners’ self-interest and a league’s self-interest.’   (ibid., p. 181).   The Premiership was formed by top clubs because they wanted a bigger slice of the available revenue, particularly television revenue which they wanted and were able to increase.   They also wanted a bigger say in how the game was run.   They succeeded in these objectives, but at the price of creating a league which can effectively only be won by three clubs (possibly four) and in which a dominance by Manchester United has been replaced by a dominance by Chelsea.   However, ‘there is no empirical evidence to suggest that leagues are far worse off when one or two clubs dominate.’   (ibid., p. 183).

Mid or lower table clubs still get bumper attendances when they play one of the top clubs, even though the outcome is relatively predictable.   It is in this area of league structure that business values have most clearly won out, with an increasing role for foreign investors even in less glamorous clubs.    Market forces and big business interests have clearly prevailed, although some fans have taken the exit with voice option, e.g., the formation of FC United by dissident Manchester United supporters.

      What is evident from this discussion is that football is a very special sector of the economy.   Brand loyalty is strong, although sometimes overstated, and demand is highly inelastic, creating an environment in which football supporters are open to exploitation with substantial transfers of funds taking place to players and their agents and occasionally owners.   The football market is, however, highly stable in terms of participants with exit (and entry) occurring rarely so that fans are usually able to continue to follow their chosen club, although the transformation of Wimbledon into Milton Keynes Dons opens the possibility of clubs being treated as franchises.    The balance of power between top clubs and the league has, however, shifted in a context in which football has become vitally important for building and retaining television audiences.    It is in this respect that the predominance of the logic of the market is most evident.

Are fans supporters or consumers?

Just as, following Hirschmann, ‘exit’ and ‘voice’ may be used as metaphors for economics and politics respectively, football fans can alternatively be constructed as ‘consumers’ (a more liberal economics perspective) or ‘supporters’ (a more community oriented political perspective).   Because exit is a difficult psychological choice for a fan, Horton (1998, p. 111) sees the language of the customer or consumer as inappropriate, arguing ‘Customers make choices, supporters do not.’   The very idea of being a supporter may be in jeopardy if the fan defines himself or herself as a consumer so that football becomes ‘a financial transaction between a seller and a buyer.’  (Horton, 1997, p. 112).   The best service is then given to the person who pays the most, and even that person is in a relatively weak position compared to institutional shareholders and sponsors.   Horton argues (1998, p. 113), ‘We should talk the language of the entitlement, not of the customer.’

     The perception of many supporters is that ‘There is a distance between football and its supporters which is … getting wider … Football has marginalised the supporters.’  (Horton, 1997, p. 183).   Some fans, however, see the way forward in being treated as a customer rather than a supporter, as the following extracts from a discussion on a football E mail list demonstrate.    Two supporters the liberal view that the market itself was empowering:

      What’s wrong with being treated like a customer?  Customers get asked their wants

      and needs and companies do their damndest to give them what they really want at a

      fair price, for fear they stop buying.  That’s what we want, isn’t it?

      Another contributor argued that the problem over the years is that customers had been treated as supporters which had been seen as a category of subordination:

      A business generally can’t be successful unless it has delivered a certain degree of

      customer satisfaction, and therefore by definition has to ‘work with’ its customers

      through market research in order to deliver the product/service they are willing to

      [continue] to buy … the sensible clubs are those who retain and build loyalty by

      understanding the wants and needs of those who align themselves with their ‘brand’

      An alternative view was:

      Customers and fans are very different and in my eyes if you are treated like a

      customer then basically the business concerned is out for itself and any attempt to

      treat customers well is only ‘because it means more profit’.   Profit is the be all and

      end all!   There lies a lot of problems with football.

      It could be that the genie of market forces is out of the bottle in football and cannot be put back in again.   Moran has noted (2003, p. 88), ‘the increasing colonization of sport by the market.  This has commonly involved much more than merely selling the activity.  It has transformed the way it is organized and even played.’   However, one should not slip too readily into a deterministic version of globalisation in which market forces sweep all before them.    There is a literature which argues that the status of consumer can be politically empowering.   Citizen consumers ‘use exit, voice, and loyalty consumer choice alternatives to express themselves politically at the marketplace.’  (Micheletti, 2003, p. 19).   Thus, ‘Consumption can in certain instances be a venue for political action.   It offers people an inroad – venue – into policymaking that otherwise may be closed to grassroots political participation.’   (Micheletti, 2003, p. 12).  

      Political consumption can thus be presented as a means of overcoming political exclusion and placing new issues on the political agenda.    In the British context, this has been developed into an analysis of a new politics of retail governance in which retailers act as more stringent and effective regulators than the state.    Retail governance is in fact problematic in a number of respects, but particular problems arise in extending the analysis to the particular case of football.    More generally, a definition of political economy has been offered as the way ‘public policy and the mass consumption economy reinforce each other’.  (Cohen, 2004, p. 8).   Whilst recognising the forces that lie behind this definition and give it its rationale, it will not be used here.

       ‘This view of consumption and consumer choice suggests that there is a politics of product, which means that every product is embedded in a political context.’   (Micheletti, 2003, p. 12).     The problem is that the political economy of football is not conducive to an effective politics of consumerism.  The basic problem is the strong loyalty of the fan to the ‘brand’, making the exit with loyalty option not particularly viable.   A decline in Premiership attendances early in the 2005-6 season did lead to something of a media panic and prompted the FA Premier League to set up an Attendances Working Party.   However, in financial terms, followers are as important as supporters and as attendances declined, viewing figures for top Premiership matches increased (not to mention the increasingly important global market for such matches in 162 countries with a global home reach of 570 million).   As a fan contributing to the E mail discussion referred to earlier noted, ‘Football should never be equated to a regular product based industry as the football supporter is a very unique type of “customer”’.  Self-definition as a customer offers the promise of autonomy and the potential of leverage, but can facilitate sophisticated forms of manipulation.

Political responses: the meta politics of club and country

Compared with an extensive literature on the economics of sport and football, the literature on its politics is more limited.  There is first a meta politics which operates at a global, but more specifically at a European level which is where the richest clubs are to be found, although external investment is now finding its way into countries like Brazil with the acquisition of Corinthians by British-based Media Sports Investment.  Much of the debate here has centred about debates about the interpretation and implementation of EU competition policy, but at the heart of these disputes is a power struggle between Fifa/Uefa representing an associative approach to the regulation of football and the G-14 (now with more than fourteen members) representing Europe’s richest clubs (although not Chelsea).   The G-14 can be seen as broadly representative of a more market oriented approach to football while Fifa likes to portray itself as the defender of the Global South and of community values.   Some of these battles are fought out on the courts, while others require winning the support of EU politicians.

       One area of conflict between Fifa/Uefa and G-14 is over the release of players for international matches.   The big clubs argue that they should be compensated for the absence of key players and more particularly when they are injured.   A court case is pending over a Moroccan player. Abdelmajid Oulmers, who was injured in an international match after his club, Royal Charleroi of Belgium, was required to release him.    Another issue is an attempt by Uefa to impose minimum quotas of home grown (strictly speaking, ‘locally trained’) players on clubs which would reverse the ceiling on the number of foreign players removed by the Bosman ruling.   The Uefa view is that cosmopolitan squads could weaken bonds with local communities, whereas the clubs want the combination of players that is most likely to win matches and attract crowds because they include what are in effect football celebrities.   Another issue which was prominent a few years ago which would have a radical impact on European football was the formation of a European football league which would be the primary competition in which top clubs would participate, although there would presumably be some form of truncated domestic qualifying competition.   That has disappeared from the agenda for now, but it could be revived.  

      More generally, G-14 wants more involvement of clubs in the management of the international game.   They have been politically skilled in their handling of EU decision-makers, who admittedly have a propensity to deal direct with big firms.   They have made use of the mechanism of the European social dialogue to hold wide-ranging talks with Fifpro, the players’ organisation.  Uefa, by contrast, has been relatively flat footed in some of its attempts to operate at an EU level, although more recently it has been concentrating some of its efforts on the five leading member states.  However, this is a contest that is by no means over with the result far from clear

The national level: a politics of cooption and engagement

Just as attempts to write off the nation-state in some parts of the globalisation literature was dangerously premature, so it would be unwise to disregard the national football associations or the relationships between clubs and national governments.   Celtic and Rangers have long had a scarcely concealed ambition to join the English Premiership.  It would give them tougher competition on a more regular basis which should have help to improve their performance in European competitions.   Instead of playing small Scottish clubs, they would meet the leading English clubs in matches that would be very attractive to television and hence enhance the clubs’ revenue streams.   However, playing south of the border would be inconsistent with the existence of a separate Scottish football association which is the basis for the (somewhat anomalous) Scottish national team.  Some Premiership clubs would also be unwilling to vote for such an extension of the Premiership’s membership as it would presumably lead to two Premiership clubs losing places in the top division they would otherwise have kept with some uncertainty about which two clubs would suffer this penalty.

      In examining national (and indeed local) football politics, a distinction is made here between a politics of cooption and engagement and a politics of resistance.   The former is a politics developed by particular clubs as a corporate strategy, while the latter involves actions by fans in defence of their vision of how football should be run.

     Charlton Athletic is taken here as an example of the politics of cooption and engagement, describing itself as ‘more than just a football club.’   Cooption refers to strategies to involve fans in the agenda of the club, while engagement refers to efforts to relate to contemporary government policy agendas.  Cooption in the case of Charlton is exemplified by the device of a supporters’ director elected by season ticket holders, although after a process of screening candidates.  However, a supporters’ director is only one voice on the board and is subject to the constraints of commercial confidentiality.   At best, they can get as an ombudsperson for fans, and could be seen by management as a way of conveying their perspective on issues to supporters.

      Charlton Athletic has followed a conscious strategy of engagement with New Labour policies.  New Labour pursued ‘a desire to use mass sport as an instrument of social policy, notably as a way of combating social exclusion and promoting public health.’  (Moran, 2003, p. 89).   It is no accident that the phrase ‘social inclusion’ appears four times in the club’s latest annual report, along with other buzz phrases such as ‘sustainable’ and ‘successful outputs’.  (Charlton Athletic, 2005, pp. 17-19). The club has pursued a multi-level governance strategy at local, regional and national political levels.   The club’s ‘key strands of community work [are thus] perceived as an innovative way of meeting the Government’s social objectives and the new Respect Policy.’  (Charlton Athletic, 2005, p. 14).   For its part the government has sent the Chancellor of the Exchequer, the then Health Secretary ‘and a delegation from the Home Office to discuss how football and sport can improve community cohesion and lead to a healthier and safer environment.’  (Charlton Athletic, 2005, p. 17).   Add in a delegation from the Belgian Government and Prince William and the club can claim:

        Such heavyweight and high profile visits have positioned the club and the

        Community Trust as a highly imaginative pathfinder contribution that can be used

        as an excellent model of best corporate social responsibility practice to roll out on a

        much wider scale in the future.   (Charlton Athletic, 2005, pp. 13-14).

The politics of resistance

Supporters have attempted to develop a politics of resistance to events affecting their clubs which they consider to be harmful to their future.    One of the earliest and most successful attempts was the formation of the Valley Party by Charlton Athletic fans who contested local elections after the local council failed to grant them planning permission to return to their ground.    After a sophisticated campaign, they gained nearly 15,000 votes and contributed to the unseating of the chair of the planning committee.  Planning permission was subsequently granted.  (Everitt, 1991).   

     The Monopolies and Mergers Commission decided to block the acquisition of Manchester United by BSKyB, a decision that ‘surprised many commentators.’ (Crowther, 2000, p. 64).   A group of  Manchester United shareholders and fans known as Shareholders United Against Murdoch (SUAM) mounted a substantial campaign against the takeover.   Many ‘did not take SUAM seriously and thought that they were pushing a very large boulder up a very steep hill.’   (Crowther, 2000, p. 70).   In opposition and in its first term in office, New Labour had expressed some sympathy for the position of football fans.  ‘New Labour’s “Charter for Football”, Blair pledged, would allow the voice of ordinary supporters to be heard in the clubs.  Market forces would not be allowed exclusive control of football’s fate.’   (Bower, 2003, p. 147).   This symbolic commitment was exemplified by the establishment of the ultimately ineffectual Football Task Force.    Such ideas as an independent football regulator have disappeared off the agenda and New Labour has reverted to the traditional government policy of nudging the FA to put its own house in order.    However, the Monopolies and Mergers Commission deciion may have been made in a broader political context that considered that fans were an important political constituency whose views should be taken into account.   The decision was significant because it prevented what could have been a more general trend for football clubs to become subsidiaries of media companies, creating a range of inherent conflicts of interest and greater pressure for ‘super leagues’.

      United fans built up a block of shares in an effort to block any further takeover, but they were unable to prevent the acquisition of the club by the Glazers who were prepared to incur heavy levels of debt to purchase what they saw as a promising sporting franchise.

The majority of shareholders saw their stake in United principally as a business transaction and were prepared to accept a good offer for their shares.   Some disgruntled United fans went off and formed a non-league team, FC United, copying an initiative by Wimbledon fans when their club was permitted to move to Milton Keynes as MK Dons. The Wimbledon decision was particularly worrying to fans because, although the football authorities argued that it was a special case, it did suggest that football clubs could be treated as franchises that could be relocated on the American model.   FC United and AFC Wimbledon have done well in terms of results and attendances, but one is left with the impression that they are morale building symbolic gestures of defiance in the face of defeat by commercial forces.

      The supporters’ trust format for involving fans in the ownership and management of a football club has won official endorsement.   It was pioneered at Northampton in 1992 where the Trust acquired seven per cent of the shares and the local authority leased out a new stadium.  (Lomax, 2000).    Lomax suggests, however, that it is important that trusts remain independent of the club:

      This, it appears to me, is the snag with the otherwise highly successful example of

      AFC Bournemouth, where a Trust, initiated by key supporters but comprising a

      coalition of local supporters, acquired the football club three years ago.   When the

      honeymoon period ends, as inevitably one day it will, whom will the supporters

      criticize?   Themselves?   And who will be in a position to represent them in doing

      so?  (Lomax, 2000, pp. 86-7).

      When Bournemouth became the first community-owned club in 1997, it was believed that the scheme would serve as a blueprint for others in the lower divisions, concentrating on raising money through areas outside football.    Money raised secured the loans for building the stadium, but with unpaid construction debts, the collapse of the ITV Digital deal, and the bottom falling out of the transfer market, the club owed the Inland Revenue about £500,000 with a total debt of around £7 million and faced administration in the closing months of 2005.   The complicated ownership arrangements at the club did not make a resolution of the problems easy, with the 2,500 fans in the trust owning a blocking golden share that constituted 51 per cent of the voting rights.   In December 2005 the club sold the ground for a property developer for £3.5m, wiping out half their debt.  They will now have to lease the ground back for around £300,000 a year.

     Supporters’ trusts have been able to find supporters with relevant business skills including solicitors and accountants and individuals with marketing expertise, but they cannot escape the economic forces faced by all lower division clubs: small gates; limited commercial, television and merchandise income; unsustainable wages; and a fall in income from transfer fees.   The inevitable result is recurring financial crises.  One solution would be to make greater use of part-time players, but the Conference and even some non-league clubs below that level have been converting to full-time squads which do make a considerable difference in terms of fitness levels and performance.

      One of the latest community owned clubs is Rushden and Diamonds which enjoy a state of the art stadium with good conference facilities.   They have also received an initial endowment of £750,000 over two years from former owner Max Griggs.   The creation of the club was essentially a personal project for Griggs who subsidised it heavily for many years until his business became less successful.   Unfortunately, the location in a largely rural area is not ideal either for attracting fans or commercial revenue.    Even after heavy cutbacks in non-playing staff, and a considerable input of volunteer labour, the club needs gates of around 3,200 – 3,000 to break even (personal information) and they are well below that level.    Supporters’ trusts may represent the embodiment of a community vision of football, but they have to operate within the logic of the market.

      A vigorous politics of resistance has been developed within football, but it has enjoyed mixed success.   Probably to be more successful it would require more systematic backing by government, but this seems unlikely, given that while there is a willingness to upbraid the football authorities about particular issues (e.g., winter postponements) this does not extend to a challenge to their regulatory autonomy.  The presence of important media interests in football may be one factor that enters into the political calculus.

Conclusions

It is evident from this discussion that football represents a product market with very distinctive features, but nevertheless some central economic concepts are useful as a device for interrogating data and undertaking analysis.   It has also been shown that football has generated both a politics of cooption and engagement by boards and resistance by fans.

     Given the distinctiveness of football, it might be asked whether it is appropriate to apply general theories of political economy.   The argument made here is that they have to be applied, both to give intellectual credulity to the enterprise and, hopefully, to make some contribution to the ongoing theoretical debate about political economy (although important issues about structure and agency have not been tackled here).   What is evident at a broad level is that we can observe in football evidence of a globalisation ‘which relies on differential modes of insertion of economies, states, regions and societies into structure of production, finance and trade.’  (Phillips, 2005c, p. 51).    Foreign investment has become an increasingly important force at the top level of football; regional political structures have become more important in its regulation; and the politics of resistance by fans has been stimulated by globalising forces, but has often been unable to overcome them.

      What remains unresolved theoretically is the appropriate integration of economics and politics (and indeed of cultural explanations that draw on sociological understandings).   There is a danger of falling into a kind of (politically popular) market failure logic in which an economic analysis is qualified by a consideration of political forces seen as a means of remedying market shortcomings.   What is evident is that the financial opportunities and prestige offered by the national state is sufficient to lure some clubs into an active engagement with the domestic political agenda, a strategy whose evident sophistication is offset by a failure to understand broader international agendas. In part the lack of political sophistication in football actually creates a problem for the insertion of relevant political science perspectives.  Fans, for their part, can easily construct themselves as ‘victims’ of forces that lie beyond their control.

       One controversial conclusion that could be drawn is that football needs more (and more sophisticated) politics not less to counter the strength of economic forces and to ensure that the game is treated as more than a marketable commodity.   In practical terms, this is a difficult project given the lack of understanding of politics, properly conceived, within football.  In intellectual terms, this would imply a need for a further development of the political analysis in this paper as part of a broader and integrated understanding of political economy.   In that sense, the paper remains tentative and there are intellectual challenges that need to be addressed.

References

Bower, T. (2003) Broken Dreams: Vanity, Greed and the Souring of British Football (London: Pocket Books).

Cameron, C. (2005), ‘Attendance Issues’, Valley Review, 31 December, 30-31.

Charlton Athletic (2005) Charlton Athletic plc: Annual Report and Accounts 2005

Cohen, E. (2004) A Consumers’ Republic: The Politics of Mass Consumption in Postwar America (New York: Vintage Books).

Conn, D. (2004) The Beautiful Game?  Searching for the Soul of Football (London: Yellow Jersey Press, 2004).

Conn, D. (2005) ‘The Beautiful Game?  Searching for the Soul of Football’, Four Four Two, August, p. 88

Crowther, P. (2000) ‘The Attempted Takeover of Manchester United by B Sky B’, in S. Hamil, J. Michie, C. Oughton and S. Whitby (eds.) Football in the Digital Age (Edinburgh: Mainstream).

Everitt, R. (1991) Battle for the Valley (London: Voice of the Valley).

Grant, W. (1982) The Political Economy of Industrial Policy (London: Butterworths)

Grant, W. (1989) Government and Industry (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).

Guilianotti, R. (2005) ‘Playing an Aerial Game: The New Political Economy of Soccer’ in J. Nauright and K.S. Schimmel (eds.) The Political Economy of Sport (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 19-37.

Hirsch, F. (1977) Social Limits to Growth (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul).

Horton, E. (1997) Moving the Goalposts: Football’s Exploitation (Edinburgh: Mainstream).

Levitt, S.D. and Dubner, S.J. (2005) Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything (London: Allen Lane).

Lomax, B. (2000) ‘Democracy and Fandom: Developing a Supporters’ Trust at Northampton Town FC’ in J. Garland, D. Malcolm and M. Rowe (eds.) The Future of Football (London: Frank Cass), 79-87.

Marwell, G. and Ames, R.E. (1981) ‘Economists Free Ride: Does Anyone Else?’,

Journal of Public Economics, 15, 295-310.

Micheletti, M. (2003) Political Virtue and Shopping: Individuals, Consumerism and Collective Action (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan).

Moran, M. (2003) The British Regulatory State (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

Murray, R. (2005) ‘Chairman’s Statement’ in Charlton Athletic plc: Annual Report and Accounts 2005, 2-5.

Phillips, N. (2004) The Southern Cone Model (London: Routledge).

Phillips, N. (2005a) ‘Whither IPE?’ in N. Phillips (ed.) Globalizing International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 246-69.

Phillips, N. (2005b) ‘State Debates in International Political Economy’ in N. Phillips (ed.) Globalizing International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 82-115.

Phillips, N. (2005c) ‘Globalization Studies in International Political Economy’ in N. Phillips (ed.) Globalizing International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 20-54.

Sandy, R., Sloane, P.J. and Rosentraub, M.S. (2004) The Economics of Sport (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan).

Schimmel, K.S. (2005) ‘Sport and Political Economy: an Introduction’ in J. Nauright and K.S. Schimmel  (eds.) The Political Economy of Sport (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 1-15.

Strange, S. (2002a) ‘Protectionism and World Politics’ in R. Tooze and C. May (eds.) Authority and Markets: Susan Strange’s Writings on International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 47-69.

Strange, S. (2002b) ‘The Persistent Myth of Lost Hegemony’ in R. Tooze and C. May (eds.) Authority and Markets: Susan Strange’s Writings on International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 121-140.

Strange, S. (2002c) ‘International Economics and International Relations: a Case of Mutual Neglect’ in R. Tooze and C. May (eds.) Authority and Markets: Susan Strange’s Writing on International Political Economy (Basingstoke: Palgrave-Macmillan), 187-196.

Szymanski, S. and Kuypers, T. (2000) Winners and Losers: the Business Strategy of Football (London: Penguin Books).

  

 {jcomments on}

                    linkedin-logo Paylaş                        Flipboard -logo Paylaş

Bu İçerik  2154  Defa Okunmuştur
 

Degerli yazarimiz Pazar, 15 Aralık 2024.

YAZARIN DIGER YAZILARINI GORMEK ICIN TIKLAYIN

Neden Futbol Ekonomisi?

 

www. Futbolekonomi.com’un  vizyon ve misyonu temel olarak  Futbol Ekonomisi Stratejik Araştırma Merkezi’nin (FESAM) vizyon ve misyonuna paralel ve aynı düzlemdedir.

 

Bu bağlamda temel misyonumuz: Futbolun yerel ve küresel makro özelliklerini incelemek ve yeni yapısal modeller önermek; bu kapsamda entelektüel gelişimi hızlandırmak ve buna ilişkin referans olabilecek bir database oluşturmak ve bunu tüm futbol araştırmacılarının emrine sunmak... Bu amaçla yapılan çalışmaları yayımlamak; gerekli her türlü bilimsel futbol araştırma ve geliştirme projelerine entelektüel anlamda destek vermek.

 

Temel Vizyonumuz: Önerilen yeni modellerin gerçekleştiğini görmektir.

 devamı >>>

finansal-futbol-anim-1

tugrulaksar_ge_roportaj

Tuğrul Akşar Güngör Urasın sorularını yanıtlıyor

  Yazar Tuğrul Akşar,
Milliyet Gazetesi Yazarı Güngör Uras'ın
sorularını yanıtlıyor.
detay için tıklayınız..

 

Spor Endexi

 

13/12/2024

Kapanış Günlük
Değişim %
  BİST 100

10125,46

+0,66

 bjk BJKAS

4,33

-0,92

 fb FENER

103,30

-0.58

 gs GSRAY

6,54

-0,91

 trabzon TSPOR

0,90

-1,10

   SPOR ENDEKSİ

3.021,26

-0,87

Videolar

Tuğrul, Tuğrul Akşar, Pusula, Ekonomi, Futbol, Futbol Ekonomi, Mali,VİDEONUN DEVAMI VE DİĞER VİDEOLAR İÇİN TIKLAYIN.

İstatistikler

İçerik Tıklama Görünümü : 44135230

TRENDYOL SÜPER LİG 2024-2025 SEZONU

  

 

 Sıra TAKIMLAR 0 G B M A Y AV

1

Galatasaray 14 12 2  0 38 15 23 38
2 Fenerbahçe 14  10   2 2 36  13   23

32

3 Samsunspor 15 9 2  4

29

17 12

29

4 Eyüpspor 15  7   5  3 24 15 9 26
5 Beşiktaş 14 7 4  3  23  15 8 25
6 Göztepe 14 7 3 4 27  20 

  7

 24 
7

Başakşehir

14 6  4  4 24 18 6 22
8 Konyaspor 15 5 4

6

17 22 -5 19
9 Rizespor 14 6 1 7 15    21  -6 19
10 Gaziantep  14 5 3 6 20 21 -1 18
11 Sivasspor 15 5 2 7

20

25   -5 17
12 Antalyaspor 14 5 3 6 18  26 -8 18
13 Trabzonspor 14 3 7

4

20  18  2  16
14 Kasımpaşa 14 3 7 4 18 21 -3 16
15 Kayserispor 14 3 6 5 15 25 -10 15
16

Alanyaspor

14

3

5 6 12 18 -6 14
17 Bodrum FK 14 3 2 9 10 21 -11 11
18 Hatayspor 14 5 8 12 23  -22 8

19

A.Demirspor 14 0 2 12 10 34 -24

 

                 

Okur Yazar


Futbolun ekonomisi, mali, hukuksal ve yönetsel kısmına ilişkin varsa makalelerinizi bize gönderin, sizin imzanızla yayınlayalım.

Yazılarınızı  info@futbolekonomi.com adresine gönderebilirsiniz. 

 

 

Annual Review of Football Finance 2023

Annual Review of Football Finance 2023

Deloitte Sports Grup'un Avrupa Futbol Finansmanına ilişkin 32. kez düzenlediği yıllık futbol finans raporuna göre, Avrupa futbol pazarı 2021 - 22 sezonunda bir önceki yıla göre %7 büyüyerek 29.5 Milyar Euro büyüklüğüne ulaştı. Rapora ulaşmak için tıklayınız

Deloitte Money League - 2024

Deloitte Money league 2024

Deloitte Money League Raporunu 27. kez yayınladı. Rapora göre Avrupa'nın en zengin 20 kulübünün 2022-23 sezonunda gelirleri toplam 10.5 Milyar Euro'ya ulaştı. Raporu okumak için tıklayınız.

UEFA Kulüp Finans&Yatırım Raporu 2024

 

UEFA Raporu-2023

UEFA Kulüp futbolunun finansal durumları ve yatırımlarına ilişkin yıllık görünüm ve benchmark raporunu yayınladı. Okumak için tıklayınız

 


 

2021-Money-league-Raporu

 

Yirmidördüncü Deloitte Money League raporuna göre Barcelona'nın 715.1 Milyon Euro'luk geliriyle ilk sırada yer aldığı, tamamı merkez lig kulüplerinden oluşan ve bir önceki yıla göre gelirleri %12 azalan Para Ligi raporunu okumak için tıklayınız

 


 

 

annual report 202021 photo

 

Avrupa Futbolunun patronu UEFA’nın gelirleri 5.7 Milyar Euro’ya Ulaştı. Raporu okumak için tıklayınız.

 


 

 UEFA-Kulup-Futbolu-Lisanslama-2023


UEFA’nın 2023’te yayınladığı en son  Kulüp Lisanslamaya İlişkin Karşılaştırma raporuna göre kulüpler Pandemi döneminde 7.3 Milyar Euro zarar ettiler. UEFA raporu, Avrupa kulüp futbolunun endişe verici bir resmini çiziyor. Raporu okumak için tıklayınız.

 


    

191112 Aktifbank Ekolig

 

Türk futbolunun gelirlerinin ve ekonomik görünümünün mercek altına alındığı Futbol Ekonomi Raporu – EkoLig'in dördüncü sayısı yayınlandı. Süper Lig’in 2017-2018 sezonu sonunda 3,2 milyar TL olan geliri, 2018-19 sezonunda 4,2 milyar TL’na ulaştı. Bkz.

 

 

master bm report lowres

 

The European Club Footballing Landscape 2022


UEFA'nın Avrupa Lulüp futboluna ilişkin 13, kez yayınladığı, Covid-19'un etkilerinin de analiz edildiği raporu okumak için Bkz.


 

 EkoSpor-y

“Ekospor’un aylık bültenlerinden haberdar olmak için tıklayınız”

 

Süper lig Marka değeri araştırma

''Taraftar Algısına Göre Türkiye Süper Ligi Marka Değerini Etkileyen Faktörlerin ve Marka Değeri Boyutlarının Değerlendirilmesi'' Prof. Dr. Musa PINAR öncülüğünde yapılan bu araştırmayı okumak için tıklayınız.

 

 

the-european-elite-2019

KPMG Avrupa’nın 32 Elit Kulübünün değerlemesini yaptı. Süper Lig’den Galatasaray ve Beşiktaş’ın da bulunduğu bu raporda en değerli kulüp 3.2 Milyar Euroluk değeriyle Real Madrid oldu. Raporu okumak için tıklayınız.
 

Endustriyel_futbol

 

Futbolda Endüstriyel Denge ve Başarı Üzerine

Futbolun Endüstriyel gelişimi, kulüplerin sportif ve iktisadi/mali yapılanışını derinden etkiliyor. Dorukhan Acar’ın Kurumsal Yönetim temelli yaklaşımı ile "Futbolda Endüstriyel Denge ve Başarı"yı okumak için tıklayınız

 

 

Türkiye'de Kadın Futbolunun Gelişimi ve Günümüzdeki Durumu

 

imagesCAVM4O4L

 

Dr. Lale ORTA’nın Kadın Futboluna Entelektüel Bir Yaklaşım Sergilediği makalesi için tıklayınız.” 

 

 

İngiliz Futbolunda Kurumsal Yönetişim Üzerine

 

governance_in_football

 

Tüm kulüplerimize ve Türk Futbol yapılanmasına farklı bir bakış açısı kazandırabileceğini düşündüğümüz, İngiliz Parlementosu’nun Kültür, medya ve spor Komitesi’nin hazırladığı raporu okumak için tıklayınız. 

 

money-and-soccer

“Money scorring goals”, Gerçekten de “Para Gol Kaydedebiliyor mu? “

Euro 2012’nin olası ekonomik etkilerini
okumak için tıklayınız. 



FFP

Futbolda Finansal Sürdürülebilirlik Kapsamında ''Finansal Fair Play Başa Baş Kuralı ve Beşiktaş Futbol Kulübü Üzerinde Bir Uygulama 
Hüseyin AKTAŞ/Salih MUTLU,

okumak için tıklayınız.